Discussion about this post

User's avatar
Ludwig Schuster's avatar

Hey Brett,

thank you for this very useful metaphor, which I have been using in some of my contexts before but not in this clarity and depth.

You describe banks‘ superpower to "issue Layer 2 chips to borrowers, in exchange for a loan agreement in which the customer promises to return a larger amount of Layer 1 money to them in future than what the chips promise to them now (in a sense, the bank ‘buys’ a higher-value long-term promise by issuing lower-value short-term promises, but exposes itself to risk in the process)."

In this paragraph an important point is missing: In most cases, for any loan agreement / credit creation banks additionally request bankable securities, some form of non-monetary assets that back up their risk in case of a loan default. Layer 2 chips issued by the banking sector are therefore i.e. mostly asset backed tokens (merely pretending to be savers‘ money, as you correctly argue).

For Layer 3 Tokens, legal compliance regarding their actual backing varies broadly.

Expand full comment
Neil Wilson's avatar

There's a few things missing from this viewpoint.

Cash is a receipt for a bank liability. In the UK a bank note is nothing more than a receipt for central bank created liabilities in the Issue Department of the Bank of England. That's it. The system is already cashless - it became that as soon as the ability to convert the notes into silver or gold coins was removed. Cash is really just a bank transfer to and from the Issue Department.

The Issue department of the Bank of England maintains balancing assets with the National Loans Fund - directly via the Ways and Means Account and Gilt issue and indirectly via the Bank of England Banking department which similarly holds Gilts as balancing assets.

The National Loans Fund has balancing item asset with the Consolidated Fund, and the Consolidated Fund holds the ultimate asset - the ability of Parliament to obtain tax from people in the denomination everybody is using. The whole of the Sterling system is a layered discounting of that power.

There's a layer 0, layer -1, and layer -2 before you reach the root of the system.

See "An Accounting Model of the UK Exchequer" for the gory details.

You may also want to explore why the liabilities in the layers are exchangeable 1-for-1 with the other layers for a particular denomination, but not between denominations. That's to do with the contractual basis of the relationship - in the UK's case the Sterling Monetary Framework which constrains a bank to behave in a particular way and subject itself to regulation, in return for the state guaranteeing that the liabilities they issue will be (largely) money good.

The banks, in effect, have become agents of the state in return for stopping the liabilities they issue from floating in value against each other.

Expand full comment
28 more comments...

No posts